2018 - 1annoSenzenze

home / Archivio / Fascicolo / Recouping Excess Pay via the Dodd-Frank Clawback

indietro stampa articolo indice fascicolo leggi articolo leggi fascicolo


Recouping Excess Pay via the Dodd-Frank Clawback

Jesse M. Fried, Nitzan Shilon

PAROLE CHIAVE: Dodd-Frank Act - USA - investitori - societŕ

Sommario:

- 1. Excess Pay and Its Costs to Investors - 1.1. The inevitability of excess pay. - 1.2. Excess pay’s costs to investors. - 2. The Inadequacy of the SOX Clawback - 2.1. Firms are failing to adopt robust excess-pay clawback policies. - 2.2. Board discretion in more than 90 percent of S&P 500 firms. - 2.3. The costs of giving directors discretion. - 2.4. Is there a benefit to board discretion? - 2.5. No misconduct, no clawback. - 3. Benefits of the Dodd-Frank Clawback Requirement - 4. Beyond Dodd-Frank: Minimizing Excess Pay from Stock Sales - 5. Conclusion - About the Authors -


The Dodd-Frank Act requires firms to adopt clawback policies for recovering certain types of excess pay – overpayments resulting from errors in performance measures (such as reported earnings). We discuss the costs of excess pay to investors, explain why most firms’ existing arrangements fall far short of what the Dodd-Frank Act is likely to require, and offer guidance to boards seeking to eliminate the types of excess pay not reached by the Dodd-Frank Act. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Dodd-Frank) requires publicly traded firms to adopt policies that compel the recovery of certain types of overpayments made to executives on the basis of financial results that turn out to be false and require a restatement. The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) is currently developing regulations to implement this new clawback policy requirement. In a recent study, we found that most firms lack a robust “excess-pay” clawback policy – one that requires firms to recover extra pay received by executives as a result of errors in performance measures 1. The absence of such a policy is likely to reduce firm value by leading to the systematic overpayment of executives and, more importantly, by weakening and distorting executives’incentives. Dodd-Frank’s clawback-policy requirement can thus be expected to improve compensation arrangements at public firms. However, in our view, Dodd-Frank’s [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


1. Excess Pay and Its Costs to Investors

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


1.1. The inevitability of excess pay.

Executives receive a substantial amount of their pay in the form of incentive compensation – equity and bonuses. Much of this incentive compensation is directly or indirectly tied to quantifiable performance measures. For example, bonuses are often directly linked to a company’s annual earnings. In addition, the payoff from executives’ sale of equity is indirectly tied to current earnings to the extent that these earnings affect the stock price. The mismeasurement of these performance metrics can lead to erroneously high payouts, or “excess pay.” In many cases, excess pay results from misconduct, such as when executives deliberately inflate earnings or other metrics to boost their own payouts. For example, Gary Winnick, the CEO of Global Crossing, sold more than $700 million worth of stock in the year before the firm filed for bankruptcy, while the company was allegedly inflating sales revenues 2. Similarly, Qwest insiders sold more than $2 billion of stock while they were overstating revenues, as the firm’s stock price dropped by over 90% from its peak 3. Unfortunately, these are not isolated cases. Empirical studies consistently report a systematic link between inflated earnings and executive stock sales 4. It is not difficult to find examples of executives who have misreported financial results to boost their bonuses. During the period 2001-2004, Fannie Mae executives received millions of [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


1.2. Excess pay’s costs to investors.

Excess pay imposes three types of costs on investors. First, whether or not executives’ receipt of excess pay results from misconduct, excess pay reduces the amount of value available to shareholders. For example, an executive who is paid $1 million based on misstated earnings, but who should have been paid $500,000 based on actual earnings, receives $500,000 that otherwise could have been distributed to shareholders or invested in the firm on their behalf. Second, the possibility of overpayment can hurt shareholders by undermining the desirable effects of incentive-based compensation arrangements. Large incentive payments are justified as necessary to motivate managers to generate firm value. Permitting executives to keep pay that is not merited by actual performance reduces the payoff differential between good and poor performance, thereby weakening pay-performance sensitivity and executives’ incentives to increase firm value. Again, this problem arises whether or not the excess pay is the result of misconduct. Third, the ability to reap excess pay via manipulation can lead executives to take steps that impose direct costs on the firm. For example, Enron executives’ manipulation of earnings destroyed a business with an estimated $30 billion of firm value 9. Even if a firm is not substantially weakened or destroyed by financial reporting manipulation, the out-of-pocket costs of such manipulation can be substantial. For instance, firms that restated [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2. The Inadequacy of the SOX Clawback

Section 304 of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) gives the SEC the ability to recoup certain payments made to executives 12. It can be applied when a firm is required to prepare an accounting restatement due to material noncompliance, as a result of misconduct, with any financial reporting requirement. In such a case, Section 304 enables the SEC to require the CEO and CFO of the firm to return to the firm any bonus or other incentive- or equity-based compensation received within 12 months of the misleading financial statement, as well as any profits realized from the sale of stock during that period 13. Notably, in the event of a required restatement and a finding of misconduct, the SEC could recover not only excess pay but all of the incentive pay received in the 12-month period following the misleading statement. Relative to a clawback targeted solely at excess pay, the SOX recovery provision appears quite punitive. However, the SOX clawback is very unlikely to be deployed, substantially reducing its deterrence (and recovery) effects. To begin with, the SOX clawback can only be deployed if there has been misconduct. As previously discussed, excess pay can impose substantial costs on investors even if there is no misconduct by diverting value from investors and undermining pay-performance sensitivity. The SOX clawback cannot do anything to mitigate these costs. Moreover, even if there has been misconduct at a particular [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2.1. Firms are failing to adopt robust excess-pay clawback policies.

Our study of S&P 500 firms indicates that, unfortunately, most firms have failed to put in place clawback policies that require them to recover excess pay resulting from errors in performance measures. While we found many gaps in the clawback policies of the firms studied, we focus on the two defects that most undermine the effectiveness of these policies. First, the overwhelming majority of S&P 500 firms gave directors discretion not to recoup excess pay. Second, most firms with clawback policies barred directors from recouping excess pay unless the executive had engaged in misconduct.

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2.2. Board discretion in more than 90 percent of S&P 500 firms.

More than 90 percent of S&P 500 firms gave directors discretion whether to recoup excess pay. To begin, nearly 50 percent of S&P 500 firms did not have any excess-pay clawback policy. Firms that lacked such a clawback policy ranged from companies with market capitalizations in the hundreds of billions of dollars, like Apple and AT&T, to smaller, less well-known firms. Directors of those firms are, of course, free to decide whether to recoup excess pay. Among the remaining S&P 500 firms that had fully disclosed excess-pay clawback policies, 81 percent gave boards discretion to let an executive keep excess-pay even if the board found that the executive had committed misconduct. Consider, for example, Procter & Gamble’s 2010 clawback policy, which states: “The Committee has adopted the Senior Executive Officer Recoupment Policy that permits the Company to recoup or ‘claw back’ certain bonus and incentive payments made to executives in the event of a significant restatement of financial results for any reason” 15. The policy fails to require the board to seek recovery of excess pay; it merely gives directors the ability to seek recovery, allowing the board to decline to recover all or any excess pay.

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2.3. The costs of giving directors discretion.

Unfortunately, directors seldom use their discretion to recover excess pay from executives. As the New York Times reported in 2005, “Companies very, very rarely – as in almost never – get that money back” 16. The reason for this reticence is simple: directors incur significant personal costs when they seek to recover excess pay from current or departed executives. Forcing a current executive to return excess pay would obviously impose a financial cost on the executive and be embarrassing, especially if the executive was responsible for the error that gave rise to the excess pay. If directors feel loyal to the executive or otherwise care about their relationships with the executive, they are likely to find it awkward to seek to recover excess pay. The board of Las Vegas Sands Corporation found itself in this position several years ago. Directors accidentally gave chairman and CEO Sheldon Adelson an extra $1 million in 2005 as a result of what the company termed an “improper interpretation” of his employment contract 17. The compensation committee voted 3-1 to allow Adelson to keep the $1 million, even though Sands’ stock had declined 18 percent during the year. The committee justified its decision based on the “outstanding performance of the company in 2005”. Of the three compensation committee members who voted to allow Adelson to keep the excess pay, two were or had been affiliated [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2.4. Is there a benefit to board discretion?

Some might argue that giving directors discretion not to recoup excess pay could benefit shareholders by allowing boards to forgo recovery in cases where the costs of a clawback are greater than the amount of excess pay. For two reasons, we find this argument unpersuasive. First, giving boards discretion is likely to drive up the cost of recovery. If an executive knows that the firm will pursue him until the excess pay is recovered, he has little incentive to resist recoupment. Thus, the cost of recovery will be low. If, on the other hand, the executive knows that directors have discretion over the recovery of excess pay, he has a strong incentive to drive up the cost of the process to deter directors. A policy requiring directors to recoup excess pay could therefore actually lower the cost of recovery. Second, even if the cost of recovery always exceeds the excess pay recouped, there are likely to be desirable deterrence effects associated with a policy requiring recoupment. Suppose, for example, that by manipulating a compensation metric, Executive A will generate excess pay of $5 million. Suppose further that the cost of recovering that excess pay is $10 million. If Executive A knows that the firm will not seek to recover the $5 million because it will cost the firm $10 million, Executive A has an incentive to manipulate the compensation metric and reap an extra $5 million at shareholders’ expense. If, on the other hand, the firm commits in advance to recover the [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


2.5. No misconduct, no clawback.

A second major problem with firms’ clawback policies is that they frequently bar recoupment in the absence of misconduct. Our study found that more than two-thirds of S&P 500 firms with clawback policies indicate that directors cannot recoup excess pay unless there is a finding of executive misconduct. In other words, an executive can keep excess pay – no matter how much – unless the company determines that the executive has committed misconduct. Consider, for example, IBM’s 2010 clawback policy: To the extent permitted by governing law, the Company will seek to recoup any bonus or incentive paid to any executive officer if (i) the amount of such payment was based on the achievement of certain financial results that were subsequently the subject of a restatement, (ii) the Board determines that such officer engaged in misconduct that resulted in the obligation to restate, and (iii) a lower payment would have been made to the officer based upon the restated financial results [[22]]. The policy commits the company to recoup an inflated bonus from an executive only if the misstatement giving rise to the excess pay was due to the executive’s misconduct. If there is no misconduct, the executive would be free to pocket the excess pay. The costs of permitting an executive to keep excess pay absent misconduct are substantial. Allowing an executive to pocket excess pay even in the absence of misconduct confers an undeserved [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


3. Benefits of the Dodd-Frank Clawback Requirement

The Dodd-Frank Act instructs the SEC to create a clawback policy requirement. Under the Act, the SEC must direct each national securities exchange to require every listed company to put in place a clawback policy to recover certain incentive compensation paid to executives when the firm is required to prepare an accounting restatement [[23]]. The clawback policy must provide that if a firm is required to restate its financial statements due to “material noncompliance” with financial reporting requirements under the securities laws, the company will recover from current and former “executive officers” any “incentive-based compensation” (including any stock option award) that is (i) based on “erroneous data,” (ii) received during the “three-year period preceding the date on which the company becomes required to prepare an accounting restatement,” and (iii) in excess of what would have been paid if calculated under the restatement. Section 954 of Dodd-Frank differs from the SOX recovery provision in a number of important ways. First, Dodd-Frank requires each firm to recover excess pay; the SOX clawback can only be invoked by the SEC. Second, the SOX clawback can be triggered only if the restatement is the result of “misconduct,” while Dodd-Frank requires recovery of excess pay even absent misconduct. Third, SOX allows the recovery of all incentive pay, while Dodd-Frank requires the clawback of only [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


4. Beyond Dodd-Frank: Minimizing Excess Pay from Stock Sales

Although Dodd-Frank’s clawback requirement will substantially improve clawback arrangements at public firms, it does have a number of limitations. Most important, Dodd-Frank does not seem to require a policy to claw back the excess proceeds from sales of stock made while the firm was inflating earnings or other metrics. Dodd-Frank requires firms to adopt a policy that will recover from an executive “who received incentive-based compensation” the “excess over what would have been paid to the executive” in the event that certain conditions are met 24. Because the proceeds of a stock sale are not “paid” by the firm, the SEC may interpret Dodd-Frank as not requiring firms to adopt a policy to recover the extra proceeds an executive receives by unwinding equity incentives at a stock price inflated by errors in performance metrics. Such an omission would be problematic even if other elements of an executive’s compensation arrangement are subject to recovery under a Dodd-Frank-compliant clawback policy. Executives will still have an incentive to manipulate earnings before they dispose of large amounts of stock. Indeed, earnings manipulation prior to stock sales has been quite common. We do not suggest trying to remedy this problem by expanding clawbacks to reach excess stock-sale proceeds (the difference between what the executive actually received selling stock and the amount that he would have received absent the metric [continua ..]

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


5. Conclusion

Executives’ receipt of excess pay imposes substantial costs on shareholders. By requiring firms to adopt policies mandating the recovery of certain types of excess pay, the Dodd-Frank Act is likely to improve compensation arrangements at public firms. However, Dodd-Frank does not reach all types of excess pay, and directors should thus take additional steps to minimize excess pay and its costs.

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


About the Authors

Jesse M. Fried is a professor at Harvard Law School, where he teaches courses in corporation law, corporate governance, executive compensation, and venture capital. He is the author of more than two dozen articles on executive compensation, insider trading, corporate governance, and venture capital. His well-known 2004 book Pay without Performance: the Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation, co-authored with professor Lucian Bebchuk, has been widely acclaimed by both academics and practitioners, and has been translated into Chinese, Japanese, and Italian. He holds an A.B. and A.M. in Economics from Harvard University, and a J.D. magna cum laude from Harvard Law School. Before joining the Harvard faculty, he was a professor of law and faculty co-director of the Berkeley Center for Law, Business and the Economy (BCLBE) at the University of California, Berkeley.  Nitzan Shilon is an SJD student at Harvard Law School. His research focuses on corporate governance and executive compensation. He received his L.L.M. from Harvard Law School, and an M.A., LL.B., and B.A. from Tel-Aviv University.

» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio


» Per l'intero contenuto effettuare il login inizio